Electoral Systems for Democratic Legislative Bodies
Policy Paper No. 82
- Written By: Nir Atmor
- Supervisor: Asher Arian
- Publication Date:
- Cover Type: Softcover
- Number Of Pages: 246 Pages
- Price: 45 NIS
This study provides an in-depth discussion of the fundamental definitions and characteristics of democratic electoral systems, as well as an up-to-date chart of the prevailing electoral systems for legislatures in the democratic world. It presents criteria for assessing electoral systems, examines the advantages and disadvantages of specific systems, points to weaknesses of the Israeli political system that are rooted in the nature of the elections and the electoral system, and proposes ways of dealing with the shortcomings of the present system.
The nature of the electoral system by which legislative representatives are chosen is one of the more controversial issues in Israel, as it is in many democracies. The type of electoral system employed in a democratic state is generally considered to have a major impact on the filling of elective office; the conduct of both the voters and their elected representatives (and the connection between them); the public agenda; and the character of democracy. As such, it is not incidental that the debate over the reform of the system of electing Knesset members has been on Israel's political agenda since the founding of the State. In ordinary times, and especially in times of crisis, critics of the present system hasten to stress its drawbacks, downplay its advantages, and call for the reform of Israel's electoral system. The reform proposals primarily focus on three central aspects:
- Proportionality of the electoral system: Optimal proportionality indicates the fair and reasonable translation of votes to seats. The proportional representation system (PR) has been employed in Israel since 1948 with minor modifications. Since 2004, the electoral threshold has been set at 2%, which means that parties that receive only 2% of the total votes win representation in the Knesset. This leads to numerous small parties, as in 2009 when 12 parties were elected to the Knesset, and thus, "excessive" proportionality.
- Electoral districts: Israel is not divided into electoral districts as is customary in the majority of states. In the absence of districts, voters have no representatives in the legislature who are accountable to their regional concerns.
- Ballot structure: Israeli voters cast votes for parties only, not for individual candidates; therefore, they have no influence on the election of particular candidates to the Knesset or on its specific composition.
With the exception of minor adjustments to the legal threshold and to the electoral formula (the method employed to translate votes into seats), and apart from the period when the direct election of the prime minister was in effect (1996-2003), every attempt to generate reform in these three areas has been unsuccessful. It is now clear that in order to offer detailed and effective proposals for changing Israel's electoral system, it is necessary to be well-acquainted with the current global situation.
The purpose of this study - Electoral Systems for Democratic Legislative Bodies - is, first and foremost, to enhance the discourse on the subject. The book provides an in-depth discussion of the fundamental definitions and characteristics of democratic electoral systems, and an up-to-date chart of the prevailing electoral systems for legislatures in the democratic world, including numerous examples of voting methods and electoral reforms. It presents desirable criteria for assessing electoral systems, and examines the advantages and disadvantages of specific systems in accordance with these benchmarks; elucidates the weaknesses of the Israeli political system that are rooted in the nature of the elections, in general, and of the electoral system, in particular; projects the results of a regional electoral system had it been introduced in the elections in 2009; and formulates recommendations for dealing with the shortcomings of the present system.
The first section of the book offers a comprehensive picture of the electoral systems in 80 democracies at the end of the first decade of the 21st century. It deals extensively with the flaws and virtues of each system, categorizing the systems employed in states currently characterized as "free democracies," according to the definition of the independent watchdog organization, Freedom House. It also cites the political processes that have recently led certain democracies to modify their electoral systems.
The first three chapters present an in-depth survey of the extensive research literature with a focus on a description of the various types of electoral systems, as well as their features and political significance. Chapter 2 enumerates eight apt criteria for a good and effective electoral system, and discusses the political debate surrounding each reform:
- Fair distribution of power among rival parties
- Balanced representation of social groups, minorities, and interest groups
- Balanced representation of districts and regions
- Governmental effectiveness and stability
- Parliamentary efficacy
- Effective political parties
- Legitimacy of the system
- Effective voter participation
The following chapters deal with three "families" of electoral systems - proportional representation (PR), plurality-majoritarian, and mixed systems - and three features of electoral systems: ballot structure, division into electoral districts, and electoral formulas. Chapter 4 deals with PR systems, focusing on Denmark's electoral system and on the recent efforts to reform the voting system in Norway. Chapter 5 addresses plurality-majoritarian electoral systems, focusing on Australia and on the reform of New Zealand's electoral system. Mixed electoral systems, the electoral system in Germany, and the repeal of Italy's mixed system are reviewed in Chapter 6. Two other complex systems, the panachage system employed in Switzerland and Luxembourg, where voters can vote for candidates of different parties, and the single transferable vote system used in Ireland and Malta are examined in Chapter 7. This section of the book provides detailed answers to the following questions:
- What are the electoral options available to voters, and what distinguishes the various types of ballots?
- What effect do electoral districts have on election results, and what forms of districting are in use in democratic countries?
- Why do numerous states use a "national compensation" system?
- How does each electoral system determine which party wins the sought-after parliamentary seats?
- What are the benefits and drawbacks of each electoral system, and what are the key arguments in favor of one as opposed to another?
- What is the potential for bias in each districting system (method of dividing a country into electoral districts)?
- Which unique features of electoral systems (ballot structure, etc., as cited above) are employed in each of the countries studied?
The second section of the book begins by identifying the weak points of the proportional electoral system in Israel using the eight criteria enumerated in the first section, which form the basis of our assessment of the various electoral systems. These weaknesses are not new - they figure prominently in the vast research literature that has delved into Israel's electoral system since the country's founding. The emphasis is on recommendations that have been debated in various frameworks, and on proposed initiatives for changing one or more components of the electoral system for the Knesset. The primary objective here is not to bring a conclusive system of recommendations, but to propose a range of valid options for change, and to examine how each reform could affect election results. The proposed reforms fall into three key groups:
- Introduction of electoral districts
- Changing the ballot structure
- Recommendations to make the electoral process more accessible and to increase voter participation
1. Introduction of electoral districts
Chapter 9 presents an analysis of the projected results of the 2009 Knesset elections had the votes been tallied using a different method than the one employed today. In the current PR electoral system, voters cast one vote for a single party. Based on the results of these elections, we conducted four simulations of moderate multi-member systems (regional electoral systems in which each district elects more than one representative to the Knesset) that are suited to Israel. In all the simulations, voters cast one vote for a single party, but in each alternative, the districting was different. We deliberately chose moderate versions of regional systems whose results would reflect adherence to the principle of proportionality and would not be radical.
- The first alternative is based on the current administrative division into 18 electoral districts as designated by the Central Elections Committee. In each district, the number of seats was allocated on the basis of the number of eligible voters in the district. The number of Knesset members representing each district - the district magnitude - was, therefore, two to eleven.
- The second alternative is also based on the administrative division by the Central Elections Committee; however, since some of the districts are very small, several of them were combined, thus reducing the number of multi-member electoral districts to 12, and increasing the district magnitude of every district - to eight to thirteen.
- The third alternative is predicated on the integration of regional elections with a "national compensation" system, which aims to reduce the distortion created by the electoral system. Here too, the administrative division of the Central Elections Committee was maintained to elect 90 Knesset members in 12 multi-member electoral districts, each of which elected six to ten representatives. The remaining 30 were elected as nationwide compensatory seats, as in the current PR system.
- The fourth alternative is similar to the third, but in this case, half of the 120 Knesset members were elected in 12 multi-member electoral districts, four to seven each, and the other 60 were elected as nationwide compensatory seats.
Each alternative was tested twice: once taking into account surplus-vote agreements between parties, and once without including such agreements. As explained in the book, surplus-vote agreements can have far-reaching effects on the distribution of political power.
It emerges from every simulation that all 12 of the political parties that won seats in the 18th Knesset (2009 elections) would have passed the legal electoral threshold and been represented in the Knesset;With the exception of two cases: the national-religious party, Jewish Home, would not have won any seats in the first alternative (18 electoral districts) or in the second alternative (12 electoral districts, with surplus-vote agreements not taken into account) in other words, the relatively high representation of social groups and ideological parties would not have been harmed in terms of the entry of their representatives in the legislature per se. However, in all four scenarios, the two major parties, Kadima and the Likud, would have benefited from the adoption of multi-member electoral districts, receiving a larger number of seats. These two parties alone would have won a minimum of 60 seats (combined) in all four multi-member systems; or more precisely, at least 62 seats in the second, third, and fourth alternatives (12 districts, taking surplus-vote agreements between parties into account), and at least 72 seats in the first alternative (18 electoral districts, without surplus-vote agreements). The simulations also indicate that the three Arab parties - Balad, United Arab List-Ta'al, and Hadash - would not have been harmed in any way by the adoption of a multi-member system.
As for the other parties, some would have maintained their power, while others would have been weakened, albeit moderately. The ultra-orthodox parties (Shas and United Torah Judaism) would have lost only a small number of seats due to the concentration of their voters in the large cities, and the Labor Party, which won 13 seats in the 2009 elections, would have been forced to cede two seats to the major parties. The parties projected to suffer a greater blow are the national-religious parties (Jewish Home and National Union), which would have been absorbed mainly by the right-wing camp, and the New Movement-Meretz, which would have been assimilated into the left-wing camp. The simulations make it clear that apart from the impact of the reform on the election results, the major contribution of a multi-member system would be the very fact of adding a regional element to the elections, whereby several Knesset members would be elected by district.
The move to regional elections could have a moderating effect, if only slightly, on unexpected election results. The reasons for this are twofold: first, the proposed multi-member electoral districts intentionally represent large geographic areas, thereby maintaining moderate proportionality in the distribution of seats; and second, two of the alternatives (the third and fourth), would give several seats as national compensation to parties harmed by the regional distribution of seats. These changes would enable regional representation, thus strengthening the connection between the voters and their elected representatives, and perhaps even reducing the number of parties winning representation in the Knesset.
2. Changing the ballot structure by adding a personal element
The study indicates that in 23 democracies with a PR system, voters have the power to influence the fate of some, or even all, the candidates on the party list. Two of the proposed changes in the design of the ballot are relatively minor: the first entails a slight modification of the existing ballot, making it "partly flexible," that is to say, in addition to voting for a party, the voter would be able to cast one personal preferential vote for the candidate on the party list that he or she considers most suitable (as is the case in several countries, for example, Austria, Denmark, and Sweden). The chief drawback of this method is that such a measure would not necessarily have an impact on the election results. A second option is to expand the ballot, meaning that the vote would still be by party, but voters would be able to cast a preferential vote for more than one candidate. This system is also known as the "semi-open system," and a similar form is customary in eight democracies (e.g., Belgium, since 2003).
The determination of the type of ballot best suited to Israel raises four issues:
- Number of votes: How many votes will each voter receive: one vote, several votes, or a number of votes based on the number of candidates in the district (if a regional system is indeed adopted)?
- Party lists at the regional level: Another issue that must be decided relates to the list of candidates that will appear on the ballot. These decisions require taking the following questions into consideration: Will every party running for election present a separate list in each of the electoral districts? If a decision is made to designate an additional level above the regional, will the names of candidates in the nationwide elections appear on the (regional) ballot as well? Will it be possible to cast a preferential vote only at the regional level, or also at the national level?
- The number of votes required to change a candidate's place on the list: It is not enough to grant each voter several votes; the number of votes (the vote quota) required to change the order of the list set by each party must be established as well.
- Surplus votes: In the case of a candidate who wins a Knesset seat, it will be necessary to decide whether surplus votes cast for this candidate are transferable to other candidates.
3. Recommendations to make the electoral process more accessible
Chapter 10 comprehensively discusses the prevailing methods employed in many democracies to encourage voter participation, and recommends the adoption of those best suited to Israel. One of the principal recommendations involves modifying the Election Law (sections 68a and 71b) to allow each person to vote at any polling station - not only at the polling station where he or she is registered (based on the voter's address listed in the Population Registry prior to the closing date of voter registration) - since the aim is to make voting easier and more accessible to the voter.
The primary conclusion arising from this study is that in order to address the shortcomings of Israel's electoral system, which have led to the weakening of the political parties, to political instability, and to increasing public mistrust of democratic institutions, it is necessary to moderately reduce the extreme proportionality that characterizes Israel's current system, while preserving the principle of representation of social groups and interest groups. The electoral reform proposed in this book aims to simultaneously maintain a just division of power between the parties, as well as to enhance regional representation and the representation of the peripheral areas in national politics; the connection between the voters and those they elect (the level of responsiveness and accountability of elected representatives must be improved); the influence of voters on the composition of party lists by adding a personal component to the ballot; and finally, voter turnout (the phenomenon of the substantially low voting rates in the 21st century is referred to as "voter fatigue"). Reform along these lines is considered appropriate and acceptable in many established democracies. It is also suited to Israel and may lead to greater political stability, as well as strengthen the government's capacity to govern.